Tuesday, 23 November 2010
Ownership & governance of critical financial infrastructure
Thursday, 18 November 2010
Governments riding in to rescue firms
What is a government to do when a company faces a near-death
situation? In almost all cases, the right answer is to let the
company go under: It is not the job of a government to prevent
companies from dying. Indeed, creative destruction is central to the
proper functioning of capitalism. Capitalism without failure is
socialism for the rich.
But sometimes, the cost-benefit ratios can look
startling. Sometimes, the disruption to the economy that comes from
the death of a company can be rather large. Let's look at three
stories.
Three examples
- GM
- In July 2009, the US government chose to put $50 billion into the
auto maker General Motors (GM) as part
of complex
rescue, which included wiping out the existing shareholders and
embarking on a complex restructuring of the firm. The old GM died
there.
GM got back to profitability this year. Seventeen months later, in
17 November, GM got back on its feet with an IPO which raised $23.1
billion. How impressive! See this
story by Michael J. de la Merced and Bill Vlasic in
the New York Times. This IPO was at $33. With this IPO, the
US Treasury got down from 61% ownership to 26% ownership, so this
IPO was the re-privatisation of GM. From here, if the US Treasury is
able to sell its remaining 0.5 billion shares at $53 a share in the
future, it will fully recoup the $50 billion that went into the
rescue (ignoring time value of money). - Satyam
- On 7 January 2009, Satyam announced that a lot of money was missing
from their balance sheet. In the aftermath of this crisis, the
government put Deepak Parekh, Kiran Karnik, Tarun Das, and three
others in charge. Read this href="http://www.livemint.com/2010/01/06212549/Deepak-Parekh--Satyam-was-res.html">interview
of Deepak Parekh with Tamal Bandyopadhyay in Mint, and this
href="http://ridingtheelephant.wordpress.com/2009/04/17/india%E2%80%99s-successful-satyam-rescue-is-the-way-to-go/">blog
post by John Elliott.
The new board put the firm up for sale. It was bought by Tech
Mahindra. A collapse of the firm was averted; the employees and
customers largely stayed in place. - UTI
- When UTI got into trouble, I was opposed to
government intervention. But by and large, I think the intervention
worked well. US-64 unitholders did suffer losses: half of the
gap between the NAV and market value was paid by the unitholders and
half by the government. And the follow-through was excellent. The
staff quality that MoF was able to muster on the problem was
outstanding. The UTI Act was repealed, and UTI was turned into an
ordinary company. `Bad UTI' was separated out by `Good UTI'. The
ownership was modified including the recent work of bringing in
T. Rowe Price as a shareholder. All in all, the exchequer did well
when selling off the shares in SUUTI. Privatisation hasn't yet come
about, but where we are is progress.
When is it right for a government to go in?
Should the US government have gone into GM? There was a fair
amount of criticism of the Obama administration for the
decision. There was concern that they were doing this owing to
pressure from trade unions. But the outcomes have been quite nice,
so (at least ex post) it looks like a good call.
In the
case of Satyam, the existing shareholders were not
expropriated. It can be argued that the failure of the firm was
not their fault. But by that argument, many firm failures in India
in the future will justify government intervention since most
public shareholders are fairly powerless when the inside
shareholders have over 50% shares. In his interview, Deepak Parekh
says Had it happened to a consumer finance company or a small,
or even big, manufacturing company, the government would not have
come out and superseded the board. The normal procedures for
bankruptcy and liquidation would have taken place.. I am not
sure how the future will work out.
The problem of execution capability
Satyam, GM and UTI are success stories in that the government
packed a mean punch in the execution. In particular, in Satyam's
case, I had simply not expected that such a nice outcome could be
achieved by the government. We should really admire the teams that
worked on these problems.
But can we count on such high quality execution on such problems in
the future? Our success in the Satyam or UTI stories should not be
generalised to the view that in the future such high quality
execution will always come about.
The exit strategy
The really amazing feature of the GM story is the clarity and
commitment of the government in getting out of `Government Motors'
by doing a privatisation just 17 months after going in. All too
often, government interventions turn into nationalisation and then
you're stuck with a public sector company for a long time, with all
the usual politics of the privatisation.
In the deep past, numerous weak companies have been nationalised
in the decades of Indian socialism (e.g. National Textile Company)
and generally the outcomes have been bad.
A particularly attractive feature of the Satyam story is that no
government money was involved. The presence of government money
makes things much harder. In India, all too often, it's easy to ask
for government money and it's easy to get it. And if the government
had got shares in Satyam, it's not easy to see how they would have
got out of it.
Similarly, a nice feature of the UTI story is that in the end, the
UTI Act was repealed, and UTI is on course for turning into a
normal financial firm. Government intervention in the rescue did not
yield an ossified PSU.
At the same time, while Satyam and UTI are good stories in terms of
the exit path, we cannot generalise too much from this given the fact
that GOI is at a
standstill on privatisation. In general, we have to assume that
what is purchased is never sold, which puts a crimp on a vast array of
situations where government intervention might be evaluated.
To summarise
When most firms approach death, the decent thing to do is to let
the firm die. We must rejoice in the extent to which Indian capitalism
is able to bring about a steady pace of firm death. Building a good
quality bankruptcy mechanism will increase the class of firms where
resolution is handled in a routine and humdrum way, without the
possibility of a special intervention. (Note that going through the
bankruptcy process was an integral part of the GM story).
When a potential
intervention situation arises, six questions need to be asked:
- Are the negative externalities of firm death really that
onerous?
- Can government intervention be envisaged without requiring
money?
- Are the Union ministers involved in the problem known for being
smart and clean?
- Can a top quality team be put together which will work on a
time-bound project starting from intervention until exit? Does this
team combine competence with cleanness?
- Do we see an exit strategy through which, within a short time,
the firm will be fully out of government hands?
- Are we very sure that in the end, we will endup imposing no
costs upon the government?
Ex post, these questions worked out well for GM, UTI and
Satyam.
Saturday, 13 November 2010
Let's go metric
Indian economics is easier in the metric system. GDP is Rs.55 trillion. The market capitalisation of Reliance is Rs.3.5 trillion. On a good day, Nifty as an underlying has derivatives turnover of Rs.1.5 trillion. A billion dollars is Rs.44 billion. When I was at the MoF, I had tried suggesting that the budget documents should be switched to metric, without success.
Sunday, 7 November 2010
Interesting readings
C. Raja
Mohan in Foreign Policy magazine on India's strategic future.
Vivek
Kulkarni in the Hindu Business Line estimates the
magnitude of corruption in Karnataka.
Ashish
Nandy in Outlook magazine on India's proclivity towards censorship.
How to improve tax compliance in
India: Thorsten
Beck, Chen Lin and Yue Ma have an article where they say that
financial development helps reduce tax evasion: when firms use more
external financing, they have greater incentive to not `cook the
books', which induces bigger tax payments.
Salil
Tripathi in Caravan magazine on improving freedom of
speech in the UK.
Robert
F. Worth in the New York Times on the shift of the
State in Saudi Arabian away from tolerating Islamic fundamentalism
to fighting it.
Who was
right: Aldous
Huxley or George Orwell?
Nicholas
Schmidle in The Atlantic with a story from Ghana about
something we badly need in India: serious investigative
journalism.
Anand
Giridharadas in the New York Times,
and Kimberly
Brooks on the Huffington Post on alternatives to the
handshake, particularly `Namaste'.
I just
read this
beautiful obituary for Milton Friedman, written by Larry Summers.
In continuation of the Indian debate on ownership and governance of
critical financial infrastructure,
see Jeremy
Grant in the Financial Times.
India's liberal foundation
But in it, I see another dimension. An upbringing in the Thackeray family is as strong an indoctrination into the sectarian perspective as you could ask for. I find it quite striking that between a certain strong ideology being sold at home, and the broader liberal worldview that pervades India, young Aditya evolved into the culture of an open and inclusive India.
The idea of India is about a great coalition of people who differ in ethnicity, language, religion, skin colour, education, income etc., who have figured out how to live together with a mixture of tolerance and individualism, without getting trapped in hatred or envy. This liberal India was strong enough to be appealing to Aditya Thackeray, and this story tells us that we're in good shape.
Friday, 5 November 2010
Why does Bombay have abysmal governance?
The resource curse
For many years, economists have been puzzled at the way things have
gone wrong in countries where natural resources were discovered. In
1993, the economist Richard M. Auty coined the phrase `Resource
curse' to convey the extent to which natural resource finds are a
curse and not a blessing. But the idea had been kicking around well
before that. I suppose it was an obvious conjecture after watching
the failures of the Middle East, where trillions of dollars of oil
revenues were squandered by not one but many countries.
In the 1970s, when oil was discovered in Venezuela, former Oil
Minister and OPEC co-founder Juan Pablo Perez
Alfonzo said:
"Ten years from now, 20 years from now, you will see, oil will bring
us ruin." His phrase for oil was: "the devil's excrement."
Why are resources a curse? In a country blessed with no natural
resources (think Japan), the only way forward for the ruling elite
is the slow hard work of building public goods, so that GDP builds
up, which then feeds back into the power and importance and utility
of the ruling elite. When the ruling elite gets their wealth for
free, without having to do the hard work of building public goods
and thus GDP of the country, the rulers emphasise the wrong
issues. That's how Venezuela ended up with Hugo Chavez.
On one hand, rulers get focused on finding ways to maximise their
rent from the underlying resource flow, without developing the
knowledge about how to build a State that delivers public goods. In
parallel, competition between politicians becomes an unpleasant
process of trying to grab the riches by means fair or foul, rather
than a process of competing in doing better on public goods. If
there are XX billion dollars to be grabbed by becoming head of
state, fairly unpleasant tactics get used by rivals aiming for that
job.
Bombay's resource curse
I just
read Maharashtra's
Audacious Chief Ministers by Ashok Malik and it is a
chilling story. It made me think: Why did governance in Bombay go
wrong so comprehensively?
Maybe the story runs like this. Winning elections in Maharashtra
does not require serving the citizens of Bombay. A party can do
various things in trying to win seats in the legislature across
Maharashtra. Once this is done, the ruling party gets the rents
that come from control of Bombay.
The wealth and prosperity of Bombay is like an oil well which is
gushing out cash for the ruling party in Maharashtra. They did not
earn it. The slow, long, hard work of learning how to run a State,
of building public goods: these things do not matter for the ruling
party in Maharashtra. They get a rental cashflow from Bombay for
free.
In (say) Jaipur, the Chief Minister and his ilk do not have an oil
well gushing cash at them. Their incentives are to worry about
public goods, and grow the GDP of Rajasthan. The importance and
rental cashflow of the leadership in Rajasthan are primarily about
the GDP of Rajasthan. Their hard work in improving public goods in
Rajasthan feeds back to them as a higher rental cashflow.
People often compare the problems with Bombay with the decline of
Calcutta after the Left took charge. The two stories are similar in
that parties which won rural votes got to run a great city into the
ground. But the Left did not take rents from Calcutta on this
scale. That was an age where the GDP of Calcutta, while impressive
by Indian standards, was still small change. Bombay of the last 20
years is in a different league altogether. This connects with the
middle
income trap meme: when capitalism first bloomed in India, some
governance problems got worse and not better.
Implications
I think this suggests that the right to govern a prosperous city
should not be based on elections taking place somewhere else. If
Bombay were a full fledged state, as Delhi is and as
the four
big cities of China are, then elections to control Bombay would
require persuading voters in Bombay.