Also see: Mobis Philipose in Mint on 13 September.
Thursday, 30 September 2010
Signs of life in stock lending
Also see: Mobis Philipose in Mint on 13 September.
Monday, 27 September 2010
Looking back at late 2008
P. Vaidyanathan Iyer has a
great first
draft of history, in the new Sunday magazine that goes with
the Indian Express, telling the story of what happened in
India in late 2008.
This was a difficult period with 6 shocks hitting us in a short
time period:
- The Lehman failure,
- The crisis on the money market,
- Difficulties at some banks,
- Difficulties in some mutual fund schemes,
- The Bombay attacks, and finally
- The Satyam crisis.
Things could have turned out much worse. The individuals at MoF,
SEBI, and RBI really came together and delivered. As India becomes a
more complex economy, it becomes more and more important to bring
top quality skills into policy making. The Indian success of crisis
management in late 2008 is tightly linked to India's success on
the
great conflicts over appointments in 2008.
Reading Vaidy's article made me go back into September and October
2008 on this blog to see what I was thinking and writing at the time:
- On 25 September, I
did a
lunch talk on the crisis at DEA. - On 29th September evening, murmurs about difficulties at ICICI
Bank erupted after the Indian market closing time. I remember how,
late in the night of the 29th, I watched the ICICI ADR trade in the
US, saw nothing big happening, did some Merton model calculations,
and thought we were okay. The next morning, I
wrote this
blog post on ICICI Bank. - This was the first day of
the 3rd
Research Meeting of the NIPFP DEA Research Program. Those
present will remember how the crisis made for a dramatic backdrop
for the inaugural session and indeed the entire conference. - On 6
October I started seeing the liquidity crisis coming together. - On 10 October, I wrote
about the
remarkable collapse in the money market which had come
about. From 13 October onwards, I started doing a series
of Crisis
Watch posts. - From 10 October onwards, Jahangir Aziz, Ila Patnaik and I started
writing a paper on what was going wrong and what should be done.
Our
paper was emailed out on 14th, we did a meeting at NIPFP to
discuss it on 18th, and finalised it on 20th. - On 26th October, I wrote about the short selling question.
When I look back, I feel that (of all people) the NIPFP
Macro/Finance Group should have quickly and clearly
understood the
linkages between multinationals and the money market, and how
the collapse of the money market in London in late September would
surely matter greatly to India. We had the building blocks: We truly
get India's high de facto integration into global finance,
and we truly get the rise of Indian multinationals as a game
changer. But we weren't cool enough to connect these pieces and make
the consequent inferences to a surprising conclusion. We only woke
up when it was obvious that the Indian money market had
collapsed.
When I look back, the really hard thing at that time was the `fog
of war' which envelops economic policy thinking. In the best of
times, the Indian statistical system is weak, and at a time like
that, the data was hopelessly out of date. We're being penny wise +
pound foolish in ignoring the informational foundations of the
economy, without which policy makers are forced to fly blind. We do
this by tolerating an
awful statistical
system, and by preventing the financial markets
which produce
vital information.
There was a lot of drama and loud opinions, but it was very hard to
figure out what was actually going on. I was also quite concerned
about Indian CEOs crying wolf in order to get money from the
government, given the long history of Indian CEOs not knowing how to
make an honest living. So I was biased in favour of ignoring the
cries at first.
Thursday, 23 September 2010
SEBI order on MCX-SX
Wednesday, 15 September 2010
Interesting readings
A big black eye for India's attempt at being a democracy. Also see Devangshu Datta in the Business Standard on this.
Interesting survey evidence in the India Today about how voters are starting to see the UPA differently. Focus on the graph in there. And here is the main story by Ashok K. Damodaran.
Nitin P. Shrivasatava, writing in DNA, says that we may finally have cracked a working mechanism to borrow shares in India. If this is the real thing, it's a big step forward for the equity market: a good stock lending mechanism is the last piece of a well functioning stock market which was absent in India. Also see Mehul Shah in the Business Standard on co-location at NSE. Maybe we're finally breaking through some of these limits of arbitrage.
The two decade gap, by Ila Patnaik in the Indian Express.
Did you know that Saudi Arabia matches India's achievements on higher education.
Jayanth Varma says that a lot might be going on in terms of INR trading outside India.
I updated my India bookshelf page.
Eric Bellman in the Wall Street Journal about the growth of McDonald's in India. Apparently a new outlet in Bhopal has been getting 10,000 visitors a day.
T. N. Ninan, writing in the Business Standard says we should move to the metric system with million, billion and trillion. I agree! GDP is Rs.55 lakh crore or Rs.55 trillion.
The 9% question by Akash Prakash, and Somasekhar Sundaresan in the Business Standard, on India's middle income trap.
Shaji Vikraman in the Economic Times on the outlook for SEBI.
Amit Tripathi in the DNA has a story about Bharti Airtel starting a price war in Kenya. Once a telecom firm has learned how to sell at Indian-style prices, it is ready to compete with telecom firms anywhere. Also see.
William Neuman has an article in the New York Times, which made me think about the appropriate role of the State, and what are actually public goods, in the field of health. Translating $0.14 into rupees yields Rs.6.5 per hen, which is feasible in India, and I'm sure that Indian drug companies would be able to get to lower pricepoints.
Skin by Mark Jacobson in the New York Magazine.
Patrick Chovanec speaks with Christina Larson in Foreign Policy, giving a glimpse into one of the last three communist countries in the world. He closes with: We look back now and it seems inevitable -- the fall of the Berlin Wall, China opening up -- but it wasn't inevitable. I'm grateful to be able to go home at the end of my trip, and I'm grateful for the people whose convictions and sacrifices made it so this kind of place is an anomaly in today's world, and not the rule.
The frontiers of computer warfare, by Fredric Paul in InformationWeek.
The great writers of the 21st century : Jonathan Franzen, David Foster Wallace.
Tim Harford in the Financial Times on the attacks on economics.
A rumination on creativity by Jonathan Lethem, in Harper's Magazine.
See this book review of Mao's Great Famine (Frank Dikotter) by Jonathan Mirsky, in the Literary Review.
Read this great interview with Tom Sargent. In particular, the chunk about how high microeconomic turbulence interacts with the welfare state to generate high and persistent unemployment.
Holman W. Jenkins in the Wall Street Journal on google.
Fred Brooks in the New York Times on how little we worry that we are wrong.
An interesting book: Better living through Economics, edited by John J. Siegfried.
Lawrence Lessig in the New Republic on the difficulties of using a government (through copyright law) to make information excludable.
David Pogue in the New York Times on the brilliant work at OpenDNS.
Patricia Cohen in the New York Times about the world of academic publishing that lies beyond peer review.
Saturday, 11 September 2010
Geniuses and economic development
On VoxEU, there is a fascinating article titled href="http://www.voxeu.org/index.php?q=node/5436">China and
India: Those two big outliers by Jesus Felipe, Utsav Kumar
and Arnelyn Abdon.
The interesting fact that they highlight is that both India and
China are wise beyond their per capita GDP when it comes to the
sophistication and diversification of their exports.
The evidence that they show, on the change in export
diversification, is quite striking:
China | India | |
1962 | 105 | 71 |
2007 | 265 | 254 |
Change (times) | 2.52x | 3.58x |
In India's case, in 1962, in the depth of India's autarky, there
were 71 commodities exported with `revealed comparative advantage'. By
2007, this number had gone up by 3.58 times. Both China and India are
outliers (with excessively high values seen for export
diversification) when compared with other countries at the same level
of per capita GDP on a PPP basis.
Explaining the unusual export diversification
One element of the explanation of diversification is sheer
size. Continental India has a diverse array of locations. Coastal
Gujarat is a good location for processing crude oil for export, and
Bihar is a good place for growing Litchis for export. By aggregating
both places into a single country, we get high levels of export
diversification. A casual examination of their graph (Figure 2) makes
me think there is some support for this conjecture - positive outliers
in the graph are big countries like the US and Germany; negative
outliers are small countries like Ireland and Finland.
Explaining the unusual export sophistication
Why does India do sophisticated export, well beyond what one would
expect for its level of per capita GDP?
- Sheer size matters. Consider the distribution of a certain
specific kind of knowledge across individuals in the country. Suppose
you set a high cutoff for the minimum knowledge required of that field
in order to assemble a large sized firm. So if you want to build a
large sized firm in that field, you need to recruit 1000 people who
have this specialised knowledge in excess of this cutoff. In a country
of 1.2 billion people, you have more draws from the same
distribution. So even if the lay of the land is quite bad in the sense
that most people have bad knowledge, the sheer size of the country
enables the establishment of firms which require building groups with
high end specialised knowledge.
Consider the distribution of IQ. One in a thousand people have an
IQ of above 146. To help fix your intution, it appears that GRE V+Q of
1450 is roughly IQ=146. In India, with a population of 1.2 billion, we
have 1.2 million of them. These 1.2 million very smart people in the
country can serve as a core around which extremely high quality firms
can be built. These effects are accentuated by increasing returns to
scale, and the operation of Metcalfe's Law, in the gains from
interaction and competition between these people within a country. - There is an odd upper tail in Indian human capital. Looking back
100 years ago, there has been a bizarre upper tail of very highly
skilled people in India. Think Ramanujan: by rights, you would have
never expected that kind of incredible knowledge to be found in a
place like India. But pre-independence India managed to have
incredible geniuses like Ramanujan, C. V. Raman, S. N. Bose and
C. R. Rao -- well before the post-independence push that created the
IITs. Is this merely about size (a lot of draws) or was there actually
a bizarre upper tail?
On this subject,
see India
shining and Bharat drowning: comparing two Indian states to the
worldwide distribution in mathematics achievement by Jishnu
Das and Tristan Zajonc. Some fascinating estimates are shown in
Producing
superstars for the economic Mundial: The team in the tail by
Lant Pritchett and Martina Viarengo, who estimate the number of 15
year olds in a country with a OECD PISA score of above 625, which is a
pretty good number. The US is estimated to have between 240,000 and
270,000 individuals in this rarefied zone. India has (a) A lot of
people, (b) An abysmally poor mode, and (b) A strange upper
tail. Putting these together, they estimate India has 100,000 and
190,000 individuals in this rarefied zone - which is incredibly
impressive considering that the Indian per capita GDP is one-thirtieth
of that seen in the US. This also tells me that we need to scale up
the universities in India so that atleast 200,000 individuals each
year are able to start a world class undergraduate education: it's a
real shame underutilising these kids.
Aside: PISA > 625 is a much weaker condition than IQ >
146.
Some people bemoan the inequality of human capital that is found in
India, i.e. the huge gap between this upper tail and the modal
value. But given that we have a low per capita GDP, would we rather
have equality where everyone has low skills, or would we rather have
an incredible upper tail in the distribution of knowledge, that is
able to learn new technology, plug into globalisation, and power the
country along?
This is also related to Albert Hirschmann's theme of unbalanced
growth: he had argued that growth involves developing an
`unbalanced' capability (e.g. India and the software industry led by
a small core of high end capabilities), and then harnessing the
benefits of the catchup by the rest of system (e.g. telecom reforms,
mass scale computer programming education, broad business skills in
running globalised firms out of India).
In a recent NBER
working paper, Eric A. Hanushek and Ludger Woessmann offer
interesting evidence about the tradeoff between `rocket scientists or
basic education for all'. They say:
Both the basic-skill and the top-performing dimensions of educational
performance appear separately important for growth. From the estimates
in column 3, a ten percentage point increase in the share of students
reaching basic literacy is associated with 0.3 percentage points
higher annual growth, and a ten percentage point increase in the share
of top-performing students is associated with 1.3 percentage points
higher annual growth....
the effect of the top-performing share is
significantly larger in countries that have more scope to catch up to
the initially most productive countries (col. 5). These results
appear consistent with a mixture of the basic models of human capital
and growth mentioned earlier. The accumulation of skills as a
standard production factor, emphasized by augmented neoclassical
growth models (e.g., Mankiw, Romer, and Weil (1992)), is probably best
captured by the basic-literacy term, which has positive effects that
are similar in size across all countries. But, the larger growth
effect of high-level skills in countries farther from the
technological frontier is most consistent with technological diffusion
models (e.g., Nelson and Phelps (1966)). From this perspective,
countries need high-skilled human capital for an imitation strategy,
and the process of economic convergence is accelerated in countries
with larger shares of high-performing students.Many countries have focused on either basic skills or engineers and
scientists. In terms of growth, our estimates suggest that developing
basic skills and highly talented people reinforce each other.
Moreover, achieving basic literacy for all may well be a precondition
for identifying those who can reach “rocket scientist” status. In
other words, tournaments among a large pool of students with basic
skills may be an efficient way to obtain a large share of
high-performers.
On a related note, it is very, very hard to create high end skills
when starting from scratch. Witness the difficulties faced by China
which had to start from scratch after destroying the elite in the
Cultural Revolution. When the economy is ready with demand for a
particular set of specialised skills, it may take decades to fill
these gaps. As an example, by the late 1980s and early 1990s, it was
obvious that there is a giant opportunity for India in software
exports and in BPO. But it took 10 years for the education system to
re-engineer itself to produce these skills in large quantities, and
then make possible large numbers for IT/ITES exports. In similar
fashion, the NDA got going on raising expenditure on infrastructure by
2003, but last month, href="http://www.nytimes.com/2010/08/26/business/global/26engineer.html?_r=3&pagewanted=all">Vikas
Bajaj has an article in the New York Times about shortages
of civil engineers. It is convenient, in economic development, to have
a pre-existing base of high-end skills ahead of time, before the phase
of high growth arrives.
Size and economic development
The argument in this blog post has emphasised size. There are many
other good things about size, such as economies of scale in the
domestic economy, and paying for the fixed costs of global firms in
learning about a country in order to do business in it.
If size is such a good thing for economic development, why has it
failed so far: as of 2010, why are India and China far behind OECD
levels of per capita GDP?
One key story lies in globalisation. Big countries feel they can
get away with autarkic policies. They feel self-sufficient and are
prone to cut themselves off from the world. Policy makers in small
countries don't think they have a choice in trying to create a
domestic car industry, but their counterparts in places like Brazil or
India or France feel they can experiment with industrial policy. Once
this problem is solved -- as seems to be partly the case with India
and China where trade liberalisation has arrived though capital
account liberalisation has not -- big countries are no longer held
back by autarkic policies. In addition, plugging into globalisation,
by itself, yields world scale, and thus boosts certain dimensions of
size.
Another story, emphasised by Lant Pritchett, lies in the extent to
which India is not a single common market, and has thus squandered
these potential gains from size. Conversely, as we strip away the
legal and tax impediments against intra-India movement of goods,
services, capital and labour, and as we bulk up on the infrastructure
of transportation and communications, we will obtain returns to size
which were not visible in the pre-2000 Indian GDP data.
Finally, on the role of size and sophisticated technological
civilisation,
see Insufficient
data on Charlie's Diary.
I am grateful to Lant Pritchett, Jishnu Das, Pratap Bhanu Mehta,
and Josh Felman for comments and improvements on this post.
Wednesday, 8 September 2010
Travails of the Indian B.Com.
Thursday, 2 September 2010
The gang that can't shoot straight
On the mistakes in the recent CSO data release,
see P. Raghavan
in the Indian Express.
By the time 3G telephony came about, India was well into the
telecom revolution. By December
2007, there
were 190 3G networks in 40 countries and 154 HSDPA networks in
71 countries, but none in India. We're
now finally
getting on with it, and will probably be the last place in the
world with 3G telephony.
And there are the failures in organising the Commonwealth Games.
It is enough to make a man worried.